Dictionnaire.enap.ca

Marie J. Bouchard, Canada Research Chair in Social SOCIAL ECONOMY Economy
Université du Québec à Montréal The social economy refers to the economic activities carried out by cooperatives, associations (or non-profit organizations), mutuals and, more recently, foundations. Often called the “third sector,” the social economy differs from the capitalist economy and public economy in that it combines private (autonomous and economic risk taking) yet collective (associative) entrepreneurship and management with goals that are not focused on profit (mutual or public interest). Social economy organizations and enterprises operate according to a common set of principles: the finality of providing services to members or the community, the democratic governance by members, and the primacy of individuals and the social objective over capital in the The social economy also refers to activities aimed at experimenting with new operating models for the economy, such as local trade systems and community currencies, fair trade, community economic development, social integration through economic activity, microfinance and solidarity Older forms of associations have existed through the ages. But the modern social economy was born in the last third of the 18th century in Europe and during the 19th century in America in reaction to the expansion of the market economy and as a result of the recognition of freedom of association (Vienney, 1980; Desroche, 1983; Gueslin, 1987; Chanial, 2009). It emerged in the wake of rural and labour movements that mixed mutual aid with production in common and called for political regulation of the economy (Petitclerc, 2007). The institution of social rights and the success of the market economy were the main reasons the social economy primarily played the role of a «sector» from the second half of the 19th century to the middle of the 20th century (Fauquet, 1965). With the crisis of Fordism and of the welfare State, new social economy organizations emerged in the 1970s and 1980s in the wake of civil society and new social movements that challenged exclusion in the spheres of work and collective services (Bélanger and Lévesque, 1992) and called for new forms of engagement in the public sphere (Eme and Laville, 1994; Laville, 1994). These organizations emerged not only to respond to social aspirations, but also to meet new needs brought on by the employment and labour crisis, the reorganization of social services, and new forms of territorial regulation (Favreau and Lévesque, 1996; Klein, 1989). Although social economy enterprises and organizations share a historical basis and common principles, they are also a heterogeneous group in a number of ways. First of all, they differ in their institutional forms, which often translate into different legal statuses. A cooperative is a group of persons that has freely gathered to meet common social, economic and cultural needs and aspirations through jointly owned and democratical y controlled enterprises that they use as consumers, workers or producers. An association (known in Quebec as a non-profit organization) is formed by at least three persons united voluntarily to carry out joint activities. Associations are subject to the constraint that they may not distribute their benefits, which may only be used to develop their activities. «Social economy» associations are those that undertake economic activities that generate goods and services used by their members or third parties. A mutual is a group of persons pursuing a social, non-profit goal that consists in offering protection to members and their families from the impacts of various social risks (illness, fire, etc.). A foundation is a non-profit legal entity created by one or more donors, which may be natural persons or legal entities, to perform charity or public interest work. Public foundations that generate goods or services and adopt a democratic decision-making process are more and more often referred to as being part of the social Different societal models exist in which the social economy assumes contrasting roles (Lévesque and Vaillancourt, 1998; Demoustier, 2001). In a welfare-State model, the social economy subsists only residually, been conceived of as strictly complementing the public network and nothing more. In a liberal or neoliberal model, where State intervention is meant to remain minimal, the social economy is in charge of non-market and redistributive activities, supported by philanthropy, volunteer work and the informal economy instead of public funding (Chaves and Monzón Campos, 2005). In an enabling-State model, a plurality of social actors share responsibilities with the State, namely the social economy, which is engaged in both market and non-market activities, with the objective of democratizing work and services, and even co-driving development through its participation in building public policies (Vaillancourt and Leclerc, 2011). These contrasted visions influence what is expected from the social economy, and orient the measures that are applied to evaluate its contribution (see Bouchard, 2009). The social economy is described according to three main theoretical approaches. In French- speaking and Latin Europe, the school of social economy combines an institutional with a normative approach that identifies legal statuses, operating rules (Vienney, 1980), values shared by organizations, democratic participation in particular, and enterprises that make up the sector (Draperi, 2007). The solidarity economy approach (Eme and Laville, 1994; Laville, 1994; Singer, 2005), which was created in France but also exists in Latin America, promotes the ties of reciprocity that characterize economic exchanges and the public space of political debates figuring in new social economy initiatives, such as local community-based service associations. Especially present in Anglo-Saxon countries, the non-profit organization (NPO) approach essentially involves associative, non-profit organizations and emphasizes the non-distribution constraint. The first major difference between these theories is that the social economy and solidarity economy approaches, with which the European social enterprise current can be associated (Borzaga and Defourny, 2001), emphasize democratic participation, an aspect ignored by the NPO approach. The other difference is that the NPO approach emphasizes the non-distribution constraint, which practically excludes most cooperatives and a large number of mutuals (Evers and Laville, 2004; For approximately thirty years now, the dominantly non-market components of the social economy (non-profit organizations and cooperatives that do not distribute dividends) have played a large role in generating social services in the public interest, while the dominantly market components (cooperatives and mutuals), which are essentially rooted in local economies, have adapted their activities to globalized markets. In the context of globalization, the social economy may be a counter-proposal to market liberalization. At the same time, however, it is at risk of being instrumentalized by States engaged in privatization, or being trivialized in a competitive environment that prompts it to opt for demutualization. Social and public recognition of the social economy can counteract such obstacles. This requires that the sector be able to communicate its specific value (Bouchard, 2009), which, though different from the market economy, public economy and household economy, also complements them (Evers and Laville, 2004). This recognition also necessitates an innovative re-examination of synergetic connections between State, the market and civil society (Lévesque, Bourque and Forgues, 2001). Bibliography
International Co-operative Alliance (2010)last retrieved on May 1, 2010). Association internationale des sociétés d'assurance mutuelle (2010).(last retrieved on Bélanger, P. et B. Lévesque (1992). “La ‘théorie’ de la régulation, du rapport salarial au rapport de consommation. Un point de vue sociologique,” Cahiers de recherche sociologique, no. 17, pp. 17-51. Borzaga, D. and J. Defourny (eds.) (2001). The Emergence of Social Enterprise, London, Routledge. Bouchard, M. (ed.) (2009). The Worth of the Social Economy: An International Perspective, Brussels, PIE Peter Chanial, P. (2009). La délicate essence du socialisme: l'association, l'individu et la République, Paris, Éditions Le Chaves, R. and J. L. Monzón Campos (2005). L'économie sociale dans l'Union européenne, Report for the Defourny, J. and P. Develtere (2009). “The Social Economy: The Worldwide Making of a Third Sector,” in J. Defourny et al., The Worldwide Making of the Social Economy: Innovations and Changes, Leuven, Acco, Demoustier, D. (2001). L'économie sociale et solidaire : s'associer pour entreprendre autrement, Paris, Syros. Desroche, H. (1983). Pour un traité d'économie sociale, Paris, Coopérative d'information et d'édition Draperi, J.-F. (2007). Comprendre l'économie sociale, fondements et enjeux, Paris, Dunod. Eme, B. and J.-L. Laville (eds.) (1994). Cohésion sociale et emploi, Paris, Desclée de Brouwer. Evers, A. and J.-L. Laville (2004). “Defining the Third Sector in Europe,” in A. Evers and J.-L. Laville (eds.), The Third Sector in Europe, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, pp. 11-42. Favreau, L. and B. Lévesque (1996). Développement économique communautaire : économie sociale et intervention, Sainte-Foy, Presses de l'Université du Québec. Fauquet, G. (1965). Le secteur coopératif, Paris, Coopérative d'information et d'édition mutualiste. Gueslin, A. (1987). L'invention de l'économie sociale : le XIXe siècle français, Paris, Economica. Klein, J.-L. (1989). “Développement régional et espace local : vers une régulation territorialisée,” Revue internationale d'action communautaire, vol. 22, no. 62, pp. 117-128. ENCYCLOPEDIC DICTIONARY OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION Laville, J.-L. (ed.) (1994). L'économie solidaire, une perspective internationale, Paris, Desclée de Brouwer (New edition 2007, Paris, Hachette Littératures). Lévesque, B., B. Bourque and E. Forgues (2001). La nouvel e sociologie économique, Paris, Desclée de Brouwer. Lévesque, B. and Y. Vaillancourt (1998). Les services de proximité au Québec : de l'expérimentation à l'institutionnalisation, Montréal, Université du Québec à Montréal. Petitclerc, M. (2007). Nous protégeons l'infortune : les origines populaires de l'économie sociale au Québec, Singer, P. (2005). “Économie solidaire 1,” in J.-L. Laville and A. D. Cattani (eds.), Dictionnaire de l'autre économie, Paris, Desclée de Brouwer, pp. 243-252. Vaillancourt, Y. with the collaboration of P. Leclerc (2011). “La coconstruction des politiques publiques. L'apport de l'économie sociale,” dans M. J. Bouchard (ed.), L'économie sociale, vecteur d'innovation : l'expérience québécoise, Québec, Presses de l'Université du Québec, pp. 115-144. Vienney, C. (1980). Socio-économie des organisations coopératives, Paris, Coopérative d'information et
REPRODUCTION
Reproduction in whole or part of the definitions contained in the Encyclopedic Dictionary of Public Administration is authorized, provided the source is acknowledged. HOW TO CITE
Bouchard, M. J. (2012). “Social Economy,” in L. Côté and J.-F. Savard (eds.), Encyclopedic Dictionary of INFORMATION
LEGAL DEPOSIT
Library and Archives Canada, 2012 | ISBN 978-2-923008-70-7 (Online)

Source: http://www.dictionnaire.enap.ca/dictionnaire/docs/definitions/definitions_anglais/social_economy.pdf

Proceeds of crime (jersey) law 1999

POLICY ON REFERRALS TO THE ATTORNEY GENERAL PROCEEDS OF CRIME (JERSEY) LAW 1999 MONEY LAUNDERING (JERSEY) ORDER 1999 On 27 January 2006, the Court of Appeal upheld the decision made by the Royal Court to convict persons for failing to comply with Article 2 (1) (a) of the Money Laundering (Jersey) Order 1999 ("the Order"). The obligation under Article 2 (1) (a), to maintai

Microsoft word - toprol physician letter 031609.doc

UPDATE: TOPROL-XL® (metoprolol succinate) now generally available after AstraZeneca delivers significant supply across the US in response to generic shortage Dear Doctor, We are pleased to provide you with follow-up information to our letter of last month regarding the availability of TOPROL-XL. As you know, after published reportsi,ii that two generic manufacturers had reca

© 2010-2018 Modern Medicine